Cost of Capital
Explicit and Implicit cost of capital
Explicit
cost of capital of any source is the discount rate that equates the
present value of cash inflows that are incremental to the taking of the
financing opportunity with the present value of its incremental cash
outflows.It is the internal rate of return cash inflows and outflows.
I=C1/(1+k)n + C2/(1+K)N+CN/(1+K)N
I=net amount of cash inflow at time zero.
C=Cash outflow at different years.
K=Explicit cost of capital
N=Number of years.
Example-
A company issues debentures of RS 100 each .The coupon rate of interest
is 10%.Maturity period 3 years.The debentures are issued at Rs 100
and redeemable at Rs 100.Calculate the explicit cost of capital.
100=10/(1+K)1+10/(1+K)2+110/(!+K)3
The discount rate which solves the equation is 10% so K is 10%.
Implicit cost of capital is also known as the opportunity cost of capital.It is rate associated with best investment opportunity.
Eg.
Mr X has a choice of investing Rs 1000 in the shares or bank
deposits.at 12%.If he invests 1000 in shares implicit cost of capital
is 12%
Cost of Debt
Debentures,Bonds,Fixed deposits,Term loans ets..Debt may be issues and redeemed at par premium or discount.
1.Debt issued at par and redeemed at par/Cost of perpetual debt(irredeemable debt.)
The before tax cost of debt(BTCD) is simply the interest offered to the suppliers of money.
BTCD= Interest/Net proceeds.
Eg. A company issues 3 years debentures of Rs 100 at 15% coupon rate .Calculate BTCD.
BTCD=15/100=15%
2.Debt issued and redeemed at discount or at a premium & Cost of existing debt.
BTCD = I + RV-NP/N
____________
RV+NP/2
RV= Redeemable value NP=Net proceeds from the issue.
N=Number of years I=Annual interest charges in rupees.
Eg.
Wipro issues 5 years 12% debentures of Rs 100 each for Rs 105.The
debentures are redeemed at par.The company has spend Rs 5 per debenture
as flotation cost.
BTCD= 12+100-100/5/100+100/2=12%
Cost of Preference Capital
These shares carry preferential rights with regard to payment of dividend and repayment of capital at
the time of winding up.The measurement of the cost of preference
capital poses some conceptual difficulty. In the case of debt, there is a
binding legal obligation on the firm to pay interest, and the interest
constitutes the basis to calculate the cost of debt. However, in the
case of preference capital, payment of dividends is not legally binding
on the firm and even if the dividends are paid, it is not a charge on
earnings; rather it is a distribution or appropriation of earnings to
preference shareholders. One may be, therefore, tempted to’ conclude
that the dividends on preference capital do not constitute cost. This is
not true .The cost of preference capital is a function of the- dividend
expected by investors. Preference capital is never issued with an
intention not to pay dividends. Although it is not legally binding upon
the firm to pay dividends on preference capital, yet it is generally
paid when the fim1 makes sufficient profits. The failure to pay
dividends, although does not cause bankruptcy, yet it can be a serious
matter from the common (ordinary) shareholders’ point of view. The
nonpayment of dividends on preference capital may result in voting
rights and control to the preference shareholders. More than this, the
firm’s credit standing may be damaged. The accumulation of preference
dividend arrears may adversely affect the prospects of ordinary
shareholders for receiving any dividends, because dividends on
preference capital represent a prior claim on profits. As a consequence,
the fim1 may find difficulty in raising funds by issuing preference or
equity shares. Also, the market value of the equity shares can be
adversely affected if dividends are not paid to the preference
shareholders and, therefore, to the equity shareholders. For these
reasons, dividends on preference capital should be paid regularly except
when the firm does not make profits, or it is in a very tight cash
position.
Irredeemable Preference Share & Redeemable Preference Share
Irredeemable Preference Share
The
preference share may be treated as a perpetual security if it is
irredeemable. Thus, its cost is given by the following equation (for a
perpetuity):
kp = DIV+RV-NP/N/RV+NP/2
where
kp is the cost of preference share, DIV is the expected preference
dividend, Rv is redeemable value,NP is net proceeds now and N is number
of years for maturity.
Redeemable Preference Share
Redeemable
preference shares (that is, preference shares with finite maturity) are
also issued in -practice. A formula similar to above Equation can be
used to compute the cost of redeemable preference share:
K=D/NP
where D is dividend outflow each year and NP is net proceeds from the issue.
The
cost of preference share is not adjusted for taxes because preference
dividend is paid after the corporate taxes have been paid. Preference
dividends do not save any taxes. Thus, the cost
of
preference share is automatically computed on after-tax basis. Since
interest is tax deductible and preference dividend is not, the after-tax
cost of preference is/ substantially higher than the
after-tax cost of debt
Cost of Equity Capital
Firms
may raise equity capital internally by retaining earnings.
Alternatively, they could distribute the entire earnings to equity
shareholders and raise equity capital externally by issuing new
shares.
In both cases, shareholders are providing funds to the firms to finance
their capital expenditures. Therefore, the equity shareholders’
required rate of return will be the same whether they supply funds by
purchasing new shares or by foregoing dividends which could have been
distributed to them. There is, however, a difference between retained
earnings and issue of equity shares from the firm’s point of view. The
firm may have to issue new shares at a price lower than the current
market price. Also, it may have to incur flotation costs. Thus, external
equity will cost more to the firm than the internal equity.
Is Equity Capital Free of Cost?
It
is sometime argued that the equity capital is free of cost. The reasons
for such argument are that it is not legally binding for firms to pay
dividends to ordinary shareholders. Further, unlike the
interest rate or preference dividend rate, the equity dividend rate is
not fixed. It is fallacious to assume equity capital to be free of cost.
As we have discussed earlier, equity capital involves an
opportunity cost; ordinary shareholders supply funds to the firm in the
expectation of dividends (including capital gains) commensurate with
their risk of investment. The market value of
the shares deter-mined by the demand and supply forces in a well
functioning capital market reflects the return required by ordinary
shareholders. Thus, the shareholders’ required rate of return,
which equates the present value of the expected dividends with the
market value of the share, is the cost of equity. The cost of external
equity could, however, be different from
the shareholders’ required rate of return if the issue price is
different from the market price of the share. In practice, it is a
formidable task to measure the cost of equity. The difficulty derives
from two factors: First, it is very difficult to estimate the expected
dividends Second, the future earnings and dividends are, expected to
grow over time. Growth in dividends should be estimated and incorporated
in the computation of the cost of equity. The estimation of growth is not an easy task.
No comments:
Post a Comment